Thursday 13 August 2020

An Open Letter to my MP about Climate Change and De-Carbonizing Transport

I have just sent an e-mail to my Member of Parliament (Jeremy Hunt) regarding the submission I made two weeks ago in response to the UK government's consultation on "de-carbonizing transport".

Here is the covering e-mail, which also draws his attention to a long, complex article I have written on lockdown actions taken against the COVID-19 virus, and how appropriate and effective they have been.

Dear Mr Hunt,

Please find attached, for your consideration as my MP, two documents on the subject of climate change and the UK government’s plans to “de-carbonize” transport. The first is a two-page letter, with a number of questions on these matters, whose relevance I very much hope you will appreciate. The second is a 56-page PDF, which I submitted two weeks ago as my response to the recent government “consultation” on these matters.

While writing, I would also like to take the opportunity to give you a link to an article I have recently written and published on the subject of lockdowns against the COVID-19 virus. The article is here: https://wattsupwiththat.com/2020/08/11/covid-19-lock-downs-or-cock-ups/.

This is, of course, an area in which as a former health secretary you have almost unrivalled expertise. My researches have led me towards the conclusion that the lockdowns, as implemented in the UK (and many other countries), have been way over the top compared to what was actually necessary. I realize you might personally disagree; but I am sure you will be aware that the longer all this stuff goes on, the less inclined ordinary people will be to give the government the benefit of the doubt.

Yours sincerely,

Neil Lock

And here is the two-page letter, with the questions:

<Address redacted>

Jeremy Hunt MP

(South West Surrey)

House of Commons

Westminster

London

SW1A 0AA

 

13 August 2020

 

Dear Mr Hunt

 

Climate Change and De-Carbonizing Transport

 

Twelve years ago, on July 14th, 2008, I wrote you a nine-page letter urging you find out the facts regarding climate change. And, having done so, to take the strongest possible stand against the UK’s Climate Change Bill. You never bothered even to acknowledge my letter, let alone reply to it. Even though I prompted you about it when you phoned me to solicit my vote the day before the 2010 election. I was, to say the least, disappointed in you.

Now, twelve years later, here we are again. But things have moved on, since you voted for that dreadful bill on that snowy night in October 2008.

Two weeks ago, I submitted a response to the government’s recent consultation on “de-carbonizing transport.” It is a 56-page PDF, and I include it in the attachments to my e-mail. I would ask you please, Mr Hunt, to read what I have to say, and to give full consideration to it. You are, after all, my one and only representative in a parliament, many of whose acts over the last year and more I consider to have gone well beyond the bounds of reasonable behaviour. By its actions the parliament has, as far as I am concerned, brought itself into disrepute. And as a result, I have now lost all respect for it.

I would like to know your views on some of the issues I raise in my document. But I won’t expect you to dig into any of the scientific detail. Your liberal-arts education, and your many years of experience with government bureaucracy, should be sufficient for you to be able to address my questions.

1.      Do you agree with the quote from Bertrand Russell, with which I begin my Preface?

2.      Would you agree that government exists to serve the people, not to rule over them against their interests?

3.      Do you agree with me when I say: “you should expect government always to be reasonable towards the people it governs?”

4.      Do you agree with me when I say that MPs: “ought always to support the interests of the people they represent against encroachment by other political interests. For example, MPs in rural areas ought to champion the car as the best means of transport for people in their areas, even when it is pooh-poohed and threatened by the big-city slickers.”

5.      Would you agree that government, and those whom it funds, should always behave with honesty, integrity and good faith towards the public?

6.      Would you agree that government must never make costly commitments on behalf of the governed without rigorous justification?

7.      Would you agree that, in a case such as the allegations that human emissions of carbon dioxide are leading to catastrophic climate change, the burden of proof should always be on the accusers to substantiate their case beyond reasonable doubt?

8.      Would you agree that the UK Interdepartmental Liaison Group on Risk Assessment’s 2002 re-formulation of the precautionary principle, which I link to from my document as reference [5], was dishonest and done in bad faith? Would you agree that it had the effect, in matters such as the “climate change” allegations, of negating the presumption of innocence, inverting the burden of proof, and requiring the accused to prove a negative?

9.      Do you think that the BBC likening allowing climate change skeptics to speak to “letting someone deny last week’s football scores” violated their own guidelines on impartiality?

10.   Would you agree that the UK government’s 2009 abandonment of the social cost approach to valuing carbon dioxide emissions when considering policies, which I link to from my document as reference [6], was dishonest and done in bad faith?

11.   Do you think that the UK government’s 2010 “Climategate” inquiries were entirely honest and done in good faith?

12.   Would you agree that Extinction Rebellion is an extremist organization, and should never have been allowed to influence UK government policy?

13.   Do you think that the Committee for Climate Change is an independent, impartial body?

14.   Do you agree with me that setting arbitrary collective targets and limits on what people may do, for example “carbon budgets,” is unjust and tyrannical?

15.   Do you think that the UK government’s plans for implementing “zero carbon,” their costs, and the consequences to the people affected by them, have been fully thought through?

16.   Would you agree that the arrogant tone of the “setting the challenge” document, in particular in its use of words and phrases like “interventions,” “behaviour change” and “accelerating modal shift,” is inappropriate to the way in which a democratic government ought to treat its people?

17.   Would you agree with me when I say: “The UK government must commission a thorough, independent, scrupulously honest, unbiased audit of its own conduct, and the conduct of those it funded, in environmental matters over the period since 1970?”

18.   And finally, if you had known in 2008 that the policies resulting from the climate change agenda would eventually have such large negative consequences for the standard and quality of living of your constituents, would you have voted for the climate change bill?

I have put my case, as fully and eloquently as I can, in my PDF document. I hope that you will feel able to take Bertrand Russell’s sage advice, and seek the facts of the matter – just as I asked you to, twelve years ago. When you have done so, I think you will find that most, if not all, of my concerns on this matter are justified. What you decide to do then will, of course, be up to you.

Yours sincerely

 

 

 

Neil Lock

P.S. I will publish this letter as “An Open Letter to my MP about Climate Change and De-Carbonizing Transport” on my own small blog http://www.honestcommonsense.co.uk/, and on another blog where I am an author. I will publish your reply on my own blog when I receive it.

Enclosure: “Response to Consultation on ‘De-Carbonizing Transport’ in the UK,” July 31st, 2020.


Tuesday 11 August 2020

COVID-19: Lock-Downs, or Cock-Ups?

This is a follow-up to my June paper on the numbers relating to the COVID epidemic world-wide. That paper is at https://wattsupwiththat.com/2020/06/20/covid-19-understanding-the-numbers-coronavirus/. This time, the main focus will be on the question: how well have lockdowns worked in different countries? I will look first at those countries in Western Europe, which show evidence (or not) of the various lockdowns having had a significant effect on the daily new case counts. Then, I will visit some of the more “interesting” countries (from a COVID statistics point of view at the present time) in other parts of the world.

As for the first paper, my data comes from Our World in Data. It can now be downloaded from https://ourworldindata.org/coronavirus-source-data. They are still keeping their spreadsheet (now 34,600 rows and counting) updated each day. They have also added a “stringency index” column to the daily record, which indicates how tightly the particular country was locked down on the particular day. I’ll discuss that soon. All the data I use in this paper came from their spreadsheet dated August 4th, 2020.

But before I begin, an explanation for non-Brits of the word “cock-up” in the title. The Cambridge Dictionary defines it as “something that is done wrong or badly.” A North American equivalent might be “snafu,” although it usually takes many cock-ups to make a full snafu. Cock-up is to snafu, roughly, as dime to dollar.

The question I aim to answer is: Is there evidence that the “lockdown” reactions to the epidemic of governments around the world have significantly helped to alleviate the effects of the virus, compared with what would have happened without those lockdowns? Or has it, perhaps, been a lot of pain for no, or little, real gain? You shall judge.

The Stringency Index

The “stringency index” is a summary number (expressed as a percentage) of how far a country is locked down. 0% is business as usual, while 100% represents maximum restrictions for all the criteria considered. The stringency data supplied to Our World in Data, and the supporting .csv file of daily data, both come from the Blavatnik School of Government, which like Our World in Data is a part of Oxford University. The file I used was the version from August 5th.

You can download the .csv file from https://www.bsg.ox.ac.uk/research/research-projects/coronavirus-government-response-tracker. (They now have an additional secondary dataset on US states’ responses to COVID-19.) The guide which explains the individual data fields is at https://github.com/OxCGRT/covid-policy-tracker/blob/master/documentation/codebook.md. The full codebook (working paper) and the documentation on the new US data are available as PDFs from https://www.bsg.ox.ac.uk/research/publications/variation-us-states-responses-covid-19.

There are nine factors included in the stringency index. They are: school closing, workplace closing, cancel public events, restrictions on gathering size, close public transport, stay at home requirements, restrictions on internal movement, restrictions on international travel, and public information campaign. In calculating the stringency index, they weight all nine factors equally; an approach which, for me at least, seems as good as any.

I did, however, identify what seem to me to be a couple of things missing from their nine-factor system. Firstly, there is no mention of mask-wearing requirements at all. And secondly, they have only a single “workplace closing” factor, whereas I would have preferred two. One for workplaces open to the public, such as shops, restaurants and bars; and one for other workplaces, such as offices and factories. This is because some countries, including the UK, have locked down considerably harder on the first than the second; and have also loosened that lockdown in several phases. It’s unfortunate that, because of the conflation of the two types of workplaces, none of these relaxations appear as changes in the stringency index for the UK at all.

All that being said, it’s the best data I’ve got, so I’m going to explore it!

The underlying mathematics

My first question on how to assess the lockdowns was: What should I plot the stringency index against, to try to get an idea of how changes in it might (or might not) have affected new cases? To make that decision, I needed to learn a (very) little about the epidemiological mathematics.

Since I was only interested in new cases, I only needed to think about one transition: the one from Susceptible to Infected. Obviously, the number of infections that are detected as new cases will depend on the level of testing being done, as well as the number of new infections. But it’s rare for the level of testing to change significantly and very suddenly. (Sweden at the beginning of June is the only case I know of). So, if I keep my time horizon short enough – say, a week – it should be a reasonable assumption that the number of new cases (eventually) detected will be roughly in proportion to the number of new infections.

Now, the most appropriate of the epidemiological models to COVID is probably the SEIR model. But if I make the (over-) simplifying assumption that the incubation period is roughly constant, then I can just use a basic SIR model. Such models have a new infection rate of the following form:

Here, N is the number of new infections per day; I the number currently infected; S the number of susceptible; P the total population; C the contacts per person per day, weighted by time spent; and τ is the transmissibility of the disease (the chance of disease transmission in a contact of a given length between a susceptible and an infectious). The units for C and τ  must be chosen so that their product τC is a dimensionless number (it is often given the symbol β).

Since, of the parameters in this equation, only C is amenable to change by individual actions or even by government edict, the intent of a lockdown must be to reduce N by reducing C. And this would still be so, even if I was using a far more complex model, with all the bells and whistles that “experts” like to hang on such things.

Thus, I would expect any lockdown which is at all effective to result in a reduction of N, and thus of the number of new cases. This reduction might occur anywhere from all but immediately, or with a delay of up to the incubation period of the virus plus however long it takes people to start complying with the lockdown. So, say, one to two weeks. On the other side, a partial or full release of a lockdown should produce a corresponding increase of , and so of the number of new cases – unless, of course, herd immunity has been nearly, or actually, reached.

An extra complication is that the number of new cases in an epidemic has its own dynamics. To mis-quote Larry Wall’s Harvard Law: “Under controlled conditions of light, temperature, humidity, social interaction and other factors, the organism will do as it damn well pleases.” So, I thought it wouldn’t be useful to try to look for the effects of lockdown or release directly in the new case numbers. Instead, I thought, I’ll look at the rate of change of new cases. The effects of a lockdown or release ought to be visible as a “knee-bend” (maybe not instantly, but certainly within a couple of weeks) in this rate of change.

How I graphed the lockdowns for the UK

In my earlier paper, I used a graph of daily growth of weekly averaged new cases, to enable me to pick out early outbreaks of the virus which were too small to be easily visible on the headline graph of daily cases and deaths. So, I adapted this into a graph of growth of new cases on a weekly basis. I started out by trying to plot the ratio of the raw new case count to the count from 7 days previously; but the data proved to be too noisy for that to be useful. So, I had to settle for the week-on-week change in new case counts which were already weekly averaged. The purist in me gags at such a kludge; but climate scientists can get away with doing such things, so why can’t I?

So, the weekly growth percentage shown for a given day is the ratio of the (already weekly averaged) new cases 4 days after that day, to the new cases 3 days before that day. The date underneath a point on the graph is as close as I could make it to the centre of the period from which its data was taken.

I also decided, in order to keep the height of the graph within reasonable bounds, to cap the weekly growth percentages at a maximum of 200%. Anything above 200% is simply shown as if it was 200%. The resulting graph for the UK, my starting point for this journey, comes out like this:

The blue line tells us that the week-on-week growth has been negative for most of the time since late April; superficially at least, good. Though it has crept up again a bit in July. It also suggests that the week-to-week new case growth had already started to come down from its peak, before any significant lockdown was put in place.

To confirm that last statement, I made a version of the graph that didn’t constrain the growth percentage to 200%. To be doubly certain, I also switched back to using the raw data instead of the weekly averaged data. The result was remarkable:

Say what? The week-on-week growth in cases was already well on its way down, before any kind of legislative lockdown was even contemplated. Now I’ll grant you, divide a small number from a noisy and uncertain distribution by another small number from the same distribution, and the result is uncertain in spades. But there’s a decline there, and it isn’t a hidden one.

Now, what might have caused this decline? My best guess is that when expanding into new, fresh fields, the virus (which takes time, 2 to 12 days I’m told, to incubate) can’t keep up with its old rate of progress. It’s always going to be the first cluster that expands fastest.

The April to July changes, on the other hand, show just as clearly on the basic daily cases and deaths graph:

The suspicious among you may be thinking: “But that isn’t a bit like the graph you showed us last time!” No, indeed. Here’s the one from six weeks ago:

The reason for this revisionist tendency in the UK’s data is that, since June, they have moved from showing new cases against the day they were reported, to showing them against the day the test was done; just as the Swedes were in the process of doing at the time of my earlier paper. The effect is to separate the main peak into two, and to move the first peak earlier by a few days. (Notice, also, that the second peak comes shortly after the Easter week-end.)

Another effect of this means of reporting – not visible on this graph, but you can see it in several other countries’ data – is that new case counts for the very latest few days will usually be understated. They will be added to as delayed test results come in. So, if you see an apparent downturn in new cases in the last few days before the end of the data, it’s very probably spurious, and should not be taken into account in any conclusions. Similarly, perhaps, for an apparent upturn; maybe reports from the cities come in quicker than those from the boondocks?

To return to the plot of weekly case growth against lockdown stringency. I used the raw daily data provided by the Blavatnik people to produce a history of the changes in UK regulations over the epidemic so far. (The texts in the “Measure” column are my own summaries, in text form, of the numeric codings which are used for each of the nine factors in the Blavatnik stringency data). Here’s the result:

Date

Measure

Scope

Stringency %

February 2nd

Co-ordinated public information campaign

National

11

March 16th

Recommended workplace closing

National

15

March 17th

Recommended public event cancellations

National

20

March 21st

Required some workplaces to close

National

30

 

Mandatory public event cancellations

National

 

March 22nd

Recommended not to travel

National

35

March 23rd

Mandatory all schools to close

National

70

 

Restrictions on small gatherings (<=10 people)

National

 

 

Required stay at home with exceptions

National

 

 

Mandatory restrictions on internal travel

National

 

March 26th

Recommended public transport closures

National

76

May 13th

Recommended stay at home

National

69

 

Mandatory restrictions on internal travel

Regional

 

June 1st

Mandatory all schools to close

Regional

68

June 8th

Quarantine international arrivals from high-risk regions

 

73

June 15th

Recommended stay at home

Regional

71

July 4th

Restrictions on small gatherings (<=10 people)

Regional

70

July 6th

Recommended not to travel

Regional

64

August 1st

Mandatory restrictions on internal travel

Regional

68

No stay-at-home measures

 

 

I was tempted to insert in there: “April 12th (Easter Sunday): Prime minister Boris Johnson comes back from the dead!”

Now, look back at that graph of weekly case growth versus stringency limit. The hypothesis that lockdowns and relaxations ought to trigger drops and increases in weekly case growth would suggest that the blue line ought to move in the opposite direction to the brown, soon – or, at most, in a week or two – after it. Since the big lockdown in March, does that graph show any evidence of such a movement? Not to my eyes. Remember, also, that shops and pubs re-opened in three phases on June 1st, June 15th and July 4th, none of which show up in the Blavatnik data. If I squint hard, I can maybe see a tiny upward knee-bend in the blue line in the first week of June; but it’s not conclusive.

A tour of Western Europe

Next, I thought, I’ll re-visit some of the Western European countries I looked at last time round. First, Iceland. Six weeks ago, it was the land of the perfect bell-curve. Now:

Hmmm… Ma Bell has spawned Baby Bell, and there’s a third bell just starting. Here are the growth rates and lockdown stringencies:

The Icelanders managed to snuff out the first phase of the epidemic completely in just two months from the first case, or six weeks from lockdown. Pretty impressive. What was it down to – low population density, good track and trace, strong Viking constitutions? Or could it have been due to the government locking down? Let’s have a look at the Icelandic timeline:

Date

Measure

Scope

Stringency %

January 23rd

Co-ordinated public information campaign

Regional

8

January 28th

Co-ordinated public information campaign

National

11

January 29th

Quarantine international arrivals from high-risk regions

 

17

March 15th

Restrictions on medium size gatherings (11-100 people)

National

25

March 16th

Required some schools to close

National

51

 

Required some workplaces to close

National

 

 

Mandatory public event cancellations

National

 

March 20th

Ban on international arrivals from some regions

 

54

May 4th

Schools open

 

46

May 25th

Workplaces open

 

36

 

Restrictions on large gatherings (101-1000 people)

National

 

June 15th

Quarantine international arrivals from high-risk regions

 

33

July 31st

Recommended workplace closing

National

40

 

Restrictions on medium size gatherings (11-100 people)

National

 

Well, there you have it. As in the UK, the weekly case growth was declining before any effects on Icelanders of even the first lockdown edict could kick in. Moreover, the first cases for more than a month appeared right after they went from banning high-risk international arrivals back to quarantining them. They did close bars and close-proximity businesses like hairdressers from late March to May. But otherwise, I think the Icelanders have got the job done; maximum protection at minimal cost. It will be interesting to see how quickly the latest outbreak of new cases dies down.

Next, to two central Western European countries I looked at in detail last time. First, Italy. Here’s the weekly case growth versus stringency:

The maximum lockdown level in Italy was 94%, and they were at over 85% all the way from March 11th to May 4th. Ouch.

Now, there are a couple of instances here of what I would have expected to see when a lockdown, which has had a real effect, is lifted. There’s a definite knee-bend in weekly case growth around May 4th, and another more debatable one about June 4th. According to the Blavatnik data, on May 4th there was a package of five measures:

1.     “Recommended workplace closing” (had previously been “Mandatory all but essential workplaces to close”),

2.     “Public transport open” (had previously been “Mandatory public transport closures”),

3.     “Recommended stay at home” (had previously been at a mixture of “Required stay at home with exceptions” and “Mandatory stay at home with minimal exceptions”),

4.     “Recommended not to travel” (had previously been “Mandatory restrictions on internal travel”),

5.     “Quarantine international arrivals from high-risk regions” (had previously been “Ban on international arrivals from some regions”).

And on June 2nd and 3rd all restrictions on travel were ended, both internal and international.

Here’s the daily cases and deaths graph:

There has been a small increase in new daily cases since early June. But it’s piffling compared with the horrors back in March. Barring some unexpected development, the Italians do seem now to be through the worst.

To Switzerland:


The measures since late April have been:

Date

Measure

Scope

Stringency %

April 27th

Required some workplaces to close (previously Mandatory all but essential workplaces to close)

National

69

May 11th

Required some schools to close (previously Mandatory all schools to close)

National

66

May 30th

Restrictions on medium size gatherings (11-100 people) (previously Restrictions on small gatherings (<=10 people))

National

63

June 6th

Schools open

National

46

Recommended workplace closing (previously Required some workplaces to close)

National

 

 

No restrictions on internal travel (previously Recommended not to travel)

National

 

June 22nd

Recommended workplace closing

Regional

35

Restrictions on very large gatherings (>1000 people)

National

 

 

No stay-at-home measures (previously Recommended stay at home)

 

 

July 3rd

Restrictions on medium size gatherings (11-100 people)

Regional

39

Two of these seem to have been followed by increases in the weekly growth rate, both a couple of weeks afterwards. One was the re-opening of many schools. The other was the major package of measures on June 6th. The change on July 3rd seems to have had a more immediate effect in the opposite direction, even though only implemented regionally.

It looks as if medium or larger gatherings of people are one of the major sources of spread of the infection. Which, indeed, was what happened over Carnival week-end in the Netherlands and Belgium at the very beginning of the outbreak. It seems that the Icelanders agree with this, since the measure they chose to enact very recently in an attempt to halt their third wave of the infection was re-lowering the limit on gathering size.

Now, for the one (I hope) you’ve all been waiting for: Sweden. Ah, Sweden.


Pay no attention to that vast crevasse in the second half of June! Sweden shut down for the 3-day long summer solstice holiday. And even COVID testing all but stopped. Remembering that the big jump at the start of June was caused by a sudden expansion of testing, it looks now as if the Swedish hands-off strategy, which so many freedom-hating moaners have criticized, may well have been right all along. (The recent apparent jump, I won’t comment on today, as it hasn’t yet gone on long enough to draw any conclusions).

Here’s the timeline:

Date

Measure

Scope

Stringency %

March 9th

Co-ordinated public information campaign

National

11

March 12th

Restrictions on large gatherings (101-1000 people)

National

17

March 18th

Recommended school closing

National

20

March 19th

Ban on international arrivals from some regions

 

29

March 25th

Recommended workplace closing

National

32

March 29th

Restrictions on medium size gatherings (11-100 people)

National

35

April 1st

Recommended public event cancellations

National

41

April 4th

Recommended not to travel

National

46

June 13th

No restrictions on internal travel

 

41

June 15th

Recommended school closing

Regional

39

Look at that graph again. By the time the stringency reached its peak on April 4th, the weekly case growth was already down below 50%, and soon approached zero. And although the stringency peaked at 46%, only the restrictions on gatherings and the ban on international arrivals from badly affected regions were actually mandatory. Moreover, the ban on international arrivals seems to have been restricted mainly to those from China, Iran and Italy.

Now, the Swedes have taken a lot of flak from the moaners for their high deaths per million (570 as at August 10th). This puts them eighth in the world in that particular stakes, though still well behind Belgium, the UK, Spain and Italy. But like those countries, a very high proportion of their COVID deaths have been in care homes. There’s not much anyone could have done about those.

The Swedes were also pro-active in upping the testing rate as early as they could. As a result, they are second among major Western European countries (behind Luxembourg and ahead of Spain) in cases per million population. On all the evidence, I think the Swedes have done as good a job as they could reasonably have been expected to do under the circumstances. They deserve a round of cheers. Skål!

But the really interesting question is this. If countries like the UK and Italy had taken the Swedish approach, instead of messing up the economy and people’s lives for months on end, would the end result in terms of COVID cases and deaths have been much, or indeed any, different? Looking at the Swedish graph during March and early April, I’m coming to doubt it.

Next, Portugal, which back in June was starting to look a bit unpredictable.


Now, that’s odd. They seemed to have it under control for a while in April, then suddenly, up she goes! At least two weeks after the last change in stringency. What the Portuguese did, so the Blavatnik data shows, is bring in mandatory travel restrictions for two short periods, April 9th to 14th and May 1st to 4th – Easter week-end and May Day week-end respectively. Maybe a lot of people just ignored the bans, particularly the second? Well, it didn’t do much harm on either occasion, as you can see from the subsequent down-turns. Since then, it doesn’t look too alarming. And there doesn’t seem to be much correlation between lockdown level and weekly case growth.

Last on my tour of Western Europe, a country I didn’t even look at last time: Luxembourg. This is the only country, among all those whose figures I’ve examined so far, which has actually gone the whole way to complete release of all lockdowns. As I noted earlier, they have the highest cases per million population among major Western European countries (over 11,000). And yet, in deaths per million (191), they are only 10th. So, they must have been doing some things right, even before it came to releasing their lockdowns.

Here are the graphs:


Now, that’s an epidemic management strategy I like. Use the first peak to work out exactly what the limits are on your health care resources. Then relax the lockdowns bit by bit, and don’t worry about how many new cases you get, until you are getting near the limits of your resources. If that does threaten to happen, re-introduce the most effective lockdown you have available.

“Genius, Holmes!” “Elementary, my dear Watson.”

So, they unlocked everything on July 16th. On July 19th, they re-introduced “Restrictions on medium size gatherings (11-100 people).” The effect, if I can believe my graphs, seems to have been both instant and spectacular. So, as the Blavatnik data tells (but my graph cuts off the day before), they unlocked again on July 28th. Well done the Letzebuergesch! (That’s what they call themselves in their own language). And now, they know they can do the same thing again if they ever need to.

It’s a pity that buffoons like Boris Johnson don’t have ideas (or even advisors) as good as these.

A whistle-stop world tour

So, let’s see how the rest of the world is doing, shall we?



The most obvious feature of the world cases graph is that the third wave of the epidemic (world-wide) is far more spread out in time than the first (mainly South and East Asian) and second (mainly Western European). It’s also fair to say that the apparent drop-off towards the end may well be an artefact, caused by late reporting of tests.

But the deaths per case graph is encouraging for the longer term. As the virus spreads, it seems to be becoming steadily less lethal. I wonder if, maybe, a less virulent strain is now mixing with the nasty one, which arrived in February in Iran, Italy and the USA? It’s even conceivable that we may not, in the end, actually need to exterminate the damned thing; it might, perhaps, mutate itself back into just another variant of its brothers, the common cold coronaviruses.

In my world tour, while I’ll usually show the lockdown graph just to give an overview, I won’t go into details. That’s because to make proper sense of the data, for most of the large countries I would need it broken down by state, province or whatever else is the local unit of sub-division.

So, I’ll start with our Iranian camel friend. He was pretty much down on his knees back in June. Has he managed to get up?


All I can say is, Ouch. Though to their credit, the Iranians have generally refrained from trying to lock down too hard.

Let’s take a look at Kuwait, about whose handling of the epidemic I had some good things to say back in June:



That’s a full 100% lockdown right there, from May 10th to May 30th. More ouch. Now I know how they produced that slowdown in cases, and now I’ve seen six more weeks of their data, I’m not so sure I was right to praise them.

How about the USA?


Is that a watershed around the middle of July? Maybe. The sustained drop in weekly case growth since mid-June looks encouraging, but there’s still a long way to go.

Canada?


Nothing much to see in the first graph, but something really weird in the second. Canada seems to have stopped reporting any stringency index figures at all since July 19th! Even the Blavatnik raw data shows “no data” for all dates since then. That, and the sudden drop in case figures right after, suggest that something is afoot. Perhaps they are following Sweden and the UK, and changing the way they allocate cases to dates? I’ll simply shrug my shoulders, and move on to Mexico.


That’s bad on both the cases and deaths fronts, and even worse when you look at the deaths per case and cases per test ratios:


But the weekly case growth graph tells another story. In fact, two stories.

First, the weekly case growth has been going, slowly but fairly surely, down since April. Long may that continue! And second, if there is a country whose data suggests that the Harvard Law is right, and this virus really just does do what it damn well pleases – no matter what governments or individuals do to try to nudge it – then Mexico is that country. I’ve only been to Mexico once, and while I do recall the people being rather noisy, I didn’t find them particularly law-breaking, compared with some other places I’ve been. So, if these lockdowns are being enforced, they aren’t having much, if any, effect. That calls into question the entire lockdown idea, and all that goes with it.

So, to South America. Brazil is more than a little like Mexico. I won’t bother with the daily cases and deaths, but here’s the lockdown graph:

The graphs from Ecuador and Chile do not fill me with any confidence that the numbers they portray are accurate enough to make it worth while publishing them. Which leaves Peru as my only other stop in South America:


There have been some significant recent upward adjustments to their deaths data, and the cases don’t seem to be going too well, either. As to lockdown, they have been up above 90% for a long time, and they don’t seem to be having much success with their cautious attempts at regional unlocks.

After all those troubles in Central and South America, my next port of call, South Africa, seems at first sight like a different and better world:


The cases per test percentage is still high and rising. But though the lockdown level is high, they have started to unlock. On July 12th, though, they mandated “Required stay at home with exceptions,” thus going back to the March régime after it had been relaxed at the beginning of June. This does appear to have been successful in terms of “turning the corner.” But whether the drop in new cases will continue, time will tell.

So, to my final continent: Asia. First, Pakistan.


They have done a lot of unlocking already, and their approach is to re-impose lockdowns at the provincial level where they are warranted. It seems to be working well for them, and I think this particular patient is probably already out of danger; if, of course, I can believe the figures in the first place. For such a big country, that’s a remarkable achievement. If it’s real, of course.

Not so for next-door India, though:

They have been all the way up to 100% lockdown, and are still almost at 80%. But nothing seems to be working for them.

My Indonesian friends, although they haven’t “turned the corner,” are doing better than the Indians. And without ever raising the lockdown level above 75%:


The one lockdown measure they have re-imposed is total closure of the borders, planned to last until September. From June 23rd to July 10th, the status was “Screening of international travellers.” My graph shows a knee-bend, which actually precedes the border closure! Perhaps they announced it some days in advance.

Singapore’s data is rather confused. I think this is because it’s a cross-roads, and so always vulnerable to new infections from outside; and yet, for economic survival, the Singaporeans can’t afford to be too strict about keeping people out. So, I’ll move on, to Japan:



So much for the idea that Japanese formality and their less physical ways of socializing would keep them safe from the dreaded COVID! But kudos to the Japanese for not panicking. Yet, at least. It will be interesting to see how this one pans out.

So, to the final stop on my world tour; the track-and-trace capital of the world, South Korea.



The level-headed Koreans, for the last few months, have let the virus bumble along at the bottom of its range, where it doesn’t pose much of a threat. They could eradicate it from their country if they wanted to. But there’s no point trying to do that until everyone else is ready to do the same.

All that said, track and trace on its own wasn’t enough for them. They took their lockdown stringency up to 82% at one point. And that included a period, from April 6th to April 19th, of “Mandatory all but essential workplaces to close.” But, while the increasing lockdowns did seem to produce “knee-bends” in the weekly case growth, they didn’t seem cumulatively to have an enormous effect. Until they were relaxed, of course.

Lock-downs, or cock-ups?

So, have the COVID lock-downs been cock-ups – or even, perhaps, fully-fledged snafus? The evidence from much of the world points, in my view, to the answer Yes. Mexico and Brazil, in particular, suggest that in those countries at least, many, if not all, of the lockdown measures haven’t had much influence on what the virus ended up doing. Sweden, too, points in this direction, as does the lack of a strong increase in new cases as the UK has slowly unlocked. The jury will not be able to bring in its verdict until full cost versus benefit analyses are in from each country; but at this point, it isn’t looking good for the Lockdown Party.

There is evidence, particularly from Sweden and Luxembourg, as well as from Belgium and the Netherlands at the very start of the epidemic, that close gatherings of many people, who stay together for a considerable time, do help to spread the virus. Those with memories may also recall religious gatherings in France and South Korea, which helped give it its start in those countries.

There is also, perhaps, some evidence from South Africa that stay-at-home restrictions help to lessen the spread of the virus. Although the measure in question has been in force for less than a month, and more time is needed to confirm its effect. In any case, confinement to barracks is a blunt instrument to bash people over the head with. On the other hand, there is evidence from Portugal that when people disobey travel restrictions, it leads to a short-term increase in new cases; but things very soon return to the course they were on before.

Another point to note is that, of the biggest countries in the world (with 2018 populations above 200 million), India, the USA, Indonesia and Brazil are all floundering; some worse than others. It seems that in epidemic control, smaller countries tend – as you might expect – to do better. Of course, due to exceptional bad luck at the start of the epidemic, you will lose some: San Marino, Andorra. But you will win others: Iceland, Liechtenstein and many more. And the “jewel in the crown,” the best example of all on how to keep death rates down and how to release lockdowns: Luxembourg.

It remains only for me to castigate the UK government for all the crap they’ve thrown at us in this “sceptred isle” over the last five months. To be fair, on the presumption that lockdowns were necessary, and would actually do what they were designed to do, the choices of what to lock down were not unreasonable compared to some other countries. But were they really necessary at all? And was the guff we were told about “not letting health care resources get overloaded,” perhaps, no more than a smokescreen put out by politicians, bureaucrats and biased media, that didn’t want to risk making the National Health Service sacred cow look bad?

But failing even to screen incoming travellers until June was a glaring error; and closing small shops was way over the top. The UK government’s attempts to slant the data on tests carried out – on which they were caught out by statistician Sir David Norgrove in early June, and by me a month later, see https://wattsupwiththat.com/2020/07/02/is-the-uk-government-misleading-the-public-on-covid-tests/ wasn’t a clever move, either. Moreover, the UK, like Italy, has been far too slow to take risks in early unlocking. As a result, there seems to be forming a “consensus” that big changes are needed in the UK’s public health systems, and perhaps even in the NHS as a whole. Some heads may roll, I expect. But not nearly enough.

…and a final trip to the Faeroes

Oh, but I’ve saved the best until last. Is there, I had been thinking, some place on the planet where the government didn’t do anything much at all about locking down, compared to other countries around the same time? Is there somewhere I can use to test the hypothesis that very few, if any, of the many and varied lockdown measures that have been implemented in different places, have shown any significant efficacy at all?

Fortunately, the answer is Yes. That place is the Faeroe Islands. What happened there is that the virus, once introduced, went through the population – of the major islands, at least – like the proverbial dose of salts. Within just a few days of the government’s first reaction, the chief medical officer was saying that he thought most of those, who were going to be infected, had already been infected. Here are the graphs:



One difficulty presents itself: there is no stringency index data for the Faeroes, even in the Blavatnik daily data. But fortunately, a kind soul has put on to the Faeroes coronavirus page at Wikipedia, https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/COVID-19_pandemic_in_the_Faroe_Islands, a detailed account. Thank you, thank you to whoever did this. It’s become fashionable in some quarters to pooh-pooh Wikipedia; but in matters like this, it is an absolutely vital resource.

Here, directly quoted from Wikipedia, is what the Faeroes government did on March 12th:

·       All international travel is strongly discouraged, unless absolutely necessary.

·       All municipalities are urged to take measures regarding passenger cruise ships on their way to the Faroe Islands.

·       Anyone arriving in the Faroe Islands from overseas must take the utmost precaution and stay at home.

·       Restrictions on visitors to hospitals and nursing homes will apply. Further guidelines will be issued by the health and local council authorities.

·       The school system, including tertiary, secondary and primary schools, will close. Students and pupils will wherever possible have access to remote teaching.

·       Children's activity centres, preschools and day care facilities will also close. Childcare will be offered to those who, for particular reasons, are not able to have their children at home during working hours.

·       All employees in the public sector who do not deal with the most essential services should work from home. Staff will receive further instructions from their respective directors.

·       Measures have already been taken in the private sector to guard against infection.

·       Bars, venues and restaurants are urged to close by 22:00 for the next two weeks.

I’m not sure they would even have bothered to do that much, if the Danes hadn’t decided to lock down the previous day. And after March 12th, the only further measure they brought in was on March 17th, that “no more than 10 people should be together at once, inside or outside.” Essentially the same restriction as in Iceland at the time. Beyond that, two fuel station chains closed their shops – but not the fuel pumps. And that was all. This is not to say that people in the Faeroes did not suffer, personally and economically; they did. Scan the footnotes to the Wikipedia article, if you seek evidence.

Now, there has recently been a new outbreak of cases in the Faeroes. How caused? Once again, Wikipedia springs to the rescue. The three first cases reported “had been attending the national festival Ólavsøka where many people gathered in Tórshavn.” My graphs show only the very start of this; and it has got worse since then. Which is unfortunate for the people of the Faeroes; but fortunate for me, because it leads me directly to my…

Conclusions

Of all the countries, the Icelanders and Faeroe Islanders got closest to right in deciding what to lock down. And the Swedes, too. You can ask: Did the Faeroe Islanders need to close all schools, when the Icelanders didn’t? Or, did the Icelanders need to close some workplaces, when the Faeroe Islanders didn’t? But these are quibbles.

It appears to me that only four of the lockdown measures, which have been used, have been proven effective. In increasing order of stringency to ordinary people:

1.     Screen arriving international travellers, and quarantine, or at need ban, those from high-risk areas.

2.     Ban football matches, public parades and large events, at which thousands may gather.

3.     Restrict the number of people who may assemble in one group, or at a small event.

4.     As an absolute last resort, confine people to their homes for a short period, with exceptions like shopping and exercise.

The effectiveness of anything beyond these four is unproven. The pain, though, is obvious.

As to relaxing lockdowns, three cheers for Luxembourg. Who, unlike many other governments, have approached the whole matter with commendable common sense.